Showing posts with label Sound Money. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Sound Money. Show all posts

Wednesday, April 10, 2013

Risk, Risk, Everywhere

We try to avoid sending our readers to anything that smacks as an advertisement to sell newsletters, but sometimes the questions are relevant enough to justify addressing them head on, even if there is a sales pitch in there. Fortunately John Mauldin not only has a good pulse on the global investment community, but any sales pitch in his material is minimal compared to the content.

So with that, we point out some serious questions and concerns he addressed in a recent email which we happen to agree with. One might ask, how can you not agree with observations from the real world? Right, well, some do, so we just want to point that out.

From John's survey of readers, he concludes:

When everything is manipulated... you don't know the TRUE value of anything, right?

The Fed-driven fixed interest rates are breaking the backs of retirees (or near retirees), who find their nest eggs dwindling unless they take larger investment risks.

And the growing federal debt and the resulting "true" inflation is eating away at investors' capital.

They see interest rate risk, inflation risk, central bank and currency debasement risk, confiscatory tax rates... and bonds on life support, running out of air.

src: How to Find REAL in a World Full of FAKE

Stocks, Bonds, and Currencies doesn't agree with everything said or implied by John Mauldin or Grant Williams, but they have a long-standing reputation that justifies considering some of what they say. If you take a look at the video, come on back and tell us what you think.

Friday, October 29, 2010

The Democratic Process of Money Meddling

"...it is prudent of the central bankers to get a feel for where disappointment would actually set in."
(Source: E-piphany)
Our friend Mr. Ashton picked up the hints from a Bloomberg report. It is important to realize prices are never objective. It's true for houses, cars, and even U.S. Treasurys. So while one can despise the actions of the central bank, it's not exactly honest to claim they are stupid. As Bloomberg reports:
The New York Fed survey ... asks about expectations for the initial size of any new program of debt purchases and the time over which it would be completed. It also asks firms how often they anticipate the Fed will re- evaluate the program, and to estimate its ultimate size.
That appears to be a pretty good line of questioning! Before they make any announcement next week (or not) they better figure out what kind of a statement is least likely to create a panic. One might even consider the expectations are so strong, if they don't announce QE2 next week we'll have a clear and noticeable collapse in something on Wednesday afternoon and on into the week. It is the fall, after all.

So it looks like the fed is actually working out the plan by getting surreptitious "feedback". It's prudent to presume an event has already been priced in by the time it happens. Even if one is skeptical of that principle, given this kind of clear signaling, the pros obviously know and are already preparing their portfolios.

Therefore, the fundamental questions investors need to get right are these:

  • a) What prices will rise when this happens? Obvously Treasurys, except the inflation factor may counter the whole supply/demand factor.

  • b) If profit taking kicks in at the announcement, where have those profits been accumulating?

  • Without the results of the survey, we peons are at a grave disadvantage trying to get those answers right. The one thing we can be sure of though, is that at 2 pm EST on November 3rd, being at your terminal with fingers nimble and ready is the wise plan.

    Sunday, March 14, 2010

    How Can Stock Market Asset Prices Fall?

    For the stock market to drop in value, something else has to be in greater demand. In the realm of paper assets, the only competition for equity is debt or debt-money, and the non-paper competition is commodities and real-estate. Let's look at each one, except real-estate, which should be clear without saying in the spring of 2010 is a non-starter.

    It's been clear for about three years now that money does not flee to hard assets when paper assets are in jeopardy. Those hard assets experience a sell off, too, as money flees in a crisis for the stability of U.S. dollars. This should be expected for some of the reasons we pointed out in November. So if the stock market has a significant sell off, don’t expect a commodity price spike. Whether one thinks it should or shouldn't is irrelevant. That fact is it hasn't done so for the last three years. If you think it should, then take the sell-off as a chance to take a position at steep discounts. We address the fallacy of the counter-argument for deflation at the end.

    We are then left with the realm of paper-assets: debt-money (currency) or debt instruments. Debt instruments can get very complicated because there are many types with a variety of risk and valuation models. However, we can simplify that into a few commonalities: short term and long term, corporate and government. There is another debt instrument that doesn't quite fit that simplification: debt derivatives. Of the collateralized debt types, they essential represent the same fundamentals as bonds, except risks are slightly lower as default risk is diversified among autonomous entities. The other common derivatives can be grouped as options, futures, or credit default swaps. Virtually all of those by definition are relativity short-term bets.

    If one is worried about equity valuations (the theme of this writing) corporate bonds would be of interest to some as bonds receive the first-fruits of cash flows and stand ahead of stock in bankruptcy (government usurpation notwithstanding). But if equity prices are at risk, corporate default risks rise, too, so prudent investors won't flee to corporate bonds in a crisis. We find ourselves left with short and long government debt, or debt derivatives, competing with equity for capital investment.

    Let's take debt derivatives now, particularly the CDS type. The only intelligent reason to sell equity for CDS is a credit crisis. This is in fact exactly what we saw in February. As the credit crisis that precipitated the change subsides, money flows back out of short term CDS instruments and back into longer term assets. While we don't have access to CDS price charts, we can certainly see the equity markets didn't stay low for long, which is consistent in fact and in theory with crisis of the past. So CDS competition is necessarily sudden or short lived, especially as CDS contracts are temporal by nature.

    The next type of debt instruments we look at are short term parking places: short-term government bonds, and short-term derivatives other than CDS. All are havens for capital in times of uncertainly. All are temporary parking places where one then reallocates into something of greater risk with more reward potential as the precipitating event subsides. The certainty of that movement is assured by monetary low-interest rate policies of central banks. No serious money manager can sit on ROI assets below 2% for long unless in fact the world experiences price deflation of all asset classes across the board. The Austrian theory of inflation arising as a consequence of money creation suggests in this season of 2010 that is an absurd expectation. The arguments to the contrary are addressed below.

    Like real-estate, it should go without saying that holding long term government bonds in an era of Keynesian expansion with extremely low interest rates as one of the most high risk (to asset price) low-yield investments of capital. Just as rolling short term bond holdings into short term bond holdings for an extended period is only sensible in an era of broad-based systemic price deflation, holding fixed rate long bonds when currencies are threatened by increasing debt, and interest rates have no where to go but up, is asking for capital loss.

    Finally, the last paper asset vying for attention of investor and speculator capital is currency. In a crisis, even after all the liquidity measures and deficit spending in the U.S., the U.S. dollar is still the target of those fleeing for safety. Again, we aren't concerned about whether that is a long term good bet, but simply recognize it as the status quo. If indeed one believes such moves are unwise in the long run, take it as an opportunity to buy more reliable dollar based assets at a discount if it should transpire. But keep in mind, when this flight to safety takes place, money that isn't secured in currency derivatives will be parked in government bonds of the currency of choice, and we’ve demonstrated those arguments only have temporary extremely short value propositions. So the fundamentals of holding "cash" (pseudonym for currency), is really just another name for a bond position, and hence currency moves will follow the fundamentals of bond investments. Since bonds of all substantive nations are basically in the same boat, we don’t expect significant changes in currency price ratios as much as we’ll see in equity positions, and of course foreigners’ demands for equities ultimately translates into foreigners’ bias for currency price ratios. We covered that topic to some degree in our September piece titled "Where is the Next Bubble?"

    Given the choices money managers have in allocating capital, there appears to be only one reason to expect any kind of significant decline in equity prices in the near term, and that's a flight to safety. Just as the financial crisis of the past faded into history, there's every reason to believe this one will play out the same. We pointed out some of those reasons in November under the title "Contagion: Been There, Done That"

    In that piece we also point out how the latter sub-crisis had less effect than the instigating crisis. We've seen this take place recently with Greece's crisis, where there was some quick and noticeable reaction to flee to dollars and push down equities and commodities, but it was short lived and of little significance. Many have tried to build the case that "this time it's different" and pull some data out of a hat that appears different. Typically what we find is that they simply were unaware of similar data that did appear last time, or they miss the similarity of essence and difference only in nomenclature of the old and new data.

    So we are left with the only variable that could explain a protracted equity bear market - positive or negative inflation. Positive inflation usually gets improperly discounted by the established world view in one of two ways -- they pick a measure of money that hasn't grown well and then conclude we'll see tame inflation or deflation, or they pick a secondary influencing factor (velocity is popular these days) and argue that it will overcome the creation of money. We've provided some links on the velocity argument back in July '09 and revealed how money supply and velocity can take some interesting forms. It is our belief that the contradictions between the Austrian school theory that inflation is a monetary phenomena, and the new school that it is a velocity issue, is simply missing the point that the Austrian school theory carries with it an inferred premise that the time between the money hitting the street and the prices showing up at retail are delayed by several months to a few years. In order for monetary inflation to not eventually show up in price inflation (either consumer or capital asset price increases), one has to permanently and systemically keep the velocity low. For nations whose people have consumer goods in abundance, inflation most likely appears in financial asset prices. For nations whose people have a higher portion of earnings going toward basic goods and services, inflation most likely appears in consumer goods.

    One could achieve low monetary velocity with an economic collapse, but no substantial and influential market participant in the global economy is working toward that goal. Every policy choice and operation is designed to get people to dump their cash for something that will provide a return. All policies are designed (intentionally or accidentally) to make holding cash a losing proposition. It's the essence of both kinds of capitalism; traditional theoretical capitalism and corrupted modern capitalism. The former objective is to use one's financial capital to produce value in goods and services to reap a return on investment. The latter objective is to use one's financial capital to make other people's money work for you. The latter is the fundamental basis of the debt-money system used by every nation on earth: leverage. With every segment of every population save a few fringe radical thinkers working toward the same objective (i.e. maximum return on investment) something global and earth shaking will have to occur to put everyone off their agenda. We aren't suggesting that can't happen, just that the most likely expectation is that it won't happen until this next round of business cycle expansion pops sometime in the teens of the 21st century.

    For the stock market to drop in value, something else has to be in greater demand. At this juncture in 2010 it goes without saying that real-estate and long bonds are non-starters. Other hard assets have proven themselves unattractive as replacements (albeit good co-equals) for equities. Being left with nothing other than short-term non-performing parking places and short term quick gains made attractive by temporary sudden shocks, there simply isn’t any real long-term asset class competition to distract the global investment community from demanding more equity positions. The prudent scholar, historian, and investor should be prepared for another cyclical equity bull market in the coming few years.

    Monday, September 21, 2009

    Why Everyone Is So Bullish on Gold

    Cliff Wachtel at Seeking Alpha asked the question today, why are "speculators" buying so much gold while "professionals" are shorting?

    It appears to us he fails to realize (or he's obfuscating his real understandings for some journalistic reason) the broader fundamental nature of where prices and value come from. By that we mean the fundamental nature as described by Ludwig von Mises' in Human Action.

    In the fall of 2008, the Federal Reserve made it abundantly clear that they would stop at nothing to ensure they could control all financial markets and keep dollars flowing. Finally, after the success at keeping security markets open, they found themselves with functional markets but little or no demand for debt. As money piled up in accounts of all kinds, they then had to worry about the collapse of money velocity.

    There is absolutely only one way to make money moving -- punish anyone who doesn't trade it (spend it) in exchange for non-money. Since they have no legislative power, the only tool is debasement and negative interest rates (charging savers for storing money instead of rewarding them with interest payments).

    Debasement was easy -- in Dec '08 and Jan '09 they announced unprecedented (in the U.S.) money creation schemes in the purchase of agency debt and U.S. Treasurys. Negative interest rates seemed to manifest themselves by the nature of the credit crisis.

    So we now find ourselves in an environment where holding cash carries a risk that has to be weighed against the risks of buying bonds, stocks, commodities, or anything else. Furthermore, add to the equation the necessity of businesses of all kinds to produce a ROI above single digits, and the natural inclination is to buy something that has potential for price appreciation or income. It's no surprise to us in this light, that equities and bonds are showing price strength in spite of so many macro-economic weaknesses and the fragility of all those green shoots.

    Enjoy for now the fact that institutions are doing the buying of equities, bonds, and commodities. When the higher costs of the latter start squeezing business profits, they will either have to raise producer and consumer prices or suffer systemic business losses.

    In the former case, PPI and CPI go up, which means the risk of "holding cash" now hits consumers with inflation -- they will start spending their cash before it's purchasing power disappears, empowering producers to raise prices (the ultimate feedback loop). In the case of the latter, shrinking profit margins will be bad for equities, which religiously motivates another round of policy changes to "stimulate" the economy, further devaluing (diluting) cash (i.e. dollars).

    Very few choices today will provide price support for purchases in either scenario of inflation or economic stimulation (i.e. more currency debasement). One of them is precious metals and their centuries-old reliability as a store of value. It's not a coincidence that some sovereign nations are thinking of gold again as they did before the prevalence of fiat currencies and floating exchange rates. The only major institutions who seem to be bucking that trend are the biggest institutions in traditional western industrial regions who pin all their hopes on fiat currencies. They are the bankers and commercial traders Cliff refers to in his post.

    Update Sept 22:
    ColdCore now reports at SeekingAlpha some details about those other sovereign nations and their interest in acquiring the "real money" that the west shuns.

    Tuesday, July 14, 2009

    Gold analysis at Seeking Alpha

    Jake Towne has done an excellent job analyzing gold prices in Unlocking the Money Matrix: Gold Price Suppression. This deserves a careful review, especially by gold owners.

    A first pass over this essay impressed us as the author uses many references to government and official documents. If we understand this correctly, the gold price is "managed" by central banks today, Paul Volker made a big mistake not to do likewise, and they won't make the same mistake this time until such time as their holdings preclude them from success. This premise is strengthened by a reference to a central bank research paper advocating just such a policy decades ago.

    Someone pointed out months ago we don't have to worry about gold confiscation in the 21st century since it isn't the basis for money any more. This article suggests that even though that's true, the price of gold is the basis for psychology and fear in the populace, and that is something "they" certainly do need to control -- all nations, not just the U.S.

    So it's interesting to consider how long they can succeed at controlling the price of gold, and what will they do when they no longer can?

    There was also an interesting reference to replacing the many foreign currencies with just a few. This reminds us of the speech at the Council on Foreign Relations we pointed out last month advocating for fewer international currencies.

    We don't believe in conspiracy theories (i.e. specific global planned and orchestrated events), but we do believe in a finite and very small universe of ideas. With billions of people and hundreds of thousands of leaders in government and business, it's not surprising for ideologies (like those at the CFR speeches) to hold sway over many powerful people who either intentionally or coincidentally align their actions to support the premises behind the conspiracies. Much like blogs and analysis hold sway over investor actions and move stocks, bonds, and currency prices in particular directions.

    Mr. Towne has done an excellent job of research. What we now need is equally excellent peer review of the hard data. Please post your analysis as it comes in.

    Tuesday, July 7, 2009

    The New World Order in Stable Global Currency

    Across the Curve recently pointed out some interesting developments in China's response to the financial crisis and their bloated dollar reserves. It should be a forgone conclusion Manhattan R/E prices will fall. No news there. But China now allows settlement in Yuan. Now that’s interesting.

    However, this argument for the value of stable exchange rates was the basis for Bretton Woods, which didn’t turn out so well.
    The architects of Bretton Woods had conceived of a system wherein exchange rate stability was a prime goal. Yet, in an era of more activist economic policy, governments did not seriously consider permanently fixed rates on the model of the classical gold standard of the nineteenth century. (source: Wikipedia)
    Go ahead, blame the collapse on the U.S., but the core fact is fixed exchange rates are really price controls on foreign exchange, with some enforcement mechanism to dictate what sovereign nations can and can’t do with fiscal and monetary policy. Notice a key phrase above, which is as true today as ever in the U.S. and every other nation: "…an era of more activist economic policy…” (read that as “managed economy”).

    History is clear, price controls inevitably lead to misallocation of scares resources and poor financial decisions, then to gray and black-markets, which in the case of forex and national policy translates into cheaters who’s self-interests trump the desires of their partners. In the case of Bretton Woods, the strain of national interests working against the rules of fixed exchange finally blew up in ’72. But notice one of the preceding problems (emphasis added):
    …The United States was running huge balance of trade surpluses, and the U.S. reserves were immense and growing… (source: Wikipedia).
    So how would a new forced stable exchange rate (i.e. if China somehow convinced the world their managed currency exchange rate to ensure vibrant exports was a better reserve system than floating U.S. dollar exchange rates) fare better in the 21st century than it did in the 20th, especially in light of the balance of trade surplus problem in the 20th century and China’s balance of trade surplus today?

    Don’t get us wrong, we're not bashing China for their response to present problems. It's natural, normal, and expected for every nation to try and keep it's citizens productive, useful, and well fed. But swapping one fiat currency for another new one doesn’t seem like it will do our children any good.

    Side Note: Turns out you can celebrate Bretton Woods 65th Anniversary this month, in case you don’t already have vacation plans. We hear New England is pretty in the summer, but the guest speakers look like the type to extol the virtues of Bretton Woods without much serious criticism of its failures or alternatives. Too bad Ron Paul, Mark Skousen, or just about anyone from the University of Chicago won’t be there to speak as an alternative voice.

    Monday, July 6, 2009

    Collapse of the Dollar? I Don't Think So

    There's a very good chance that dollar will decline in value relative to many currencies in the next few years. But to call it a collapse is hyperbole. Even if it collapses like the stock market did the previous two years, it would still be less than a 50% correction other than a very short-term steep trough at the zenith. As we pointed out in June, Robert Prechter is the only reputable analyst declaring equity investments dead.

    Nevertheless, the hottest topic these days seems to be the collapse of the dollar because of America's horrendous debt load, the Fed's quantitative easing, loss of world reserve status, and who knows what else. We here at SBC would be inclined to bet you could find someone blame the dollar's demise on global warming, even.

    Well, lets see if we can compare the British pound history to the same argument about reserve status. In the 18th century, the pound was the most equivalent asset to today's reserve currency, if you leave gold out of the discussion. At that time, it traded in the 20-cent range (relative to the U.S. dollar). The question of value is one of the most clearly subjective questions one can think of. Lucky for us someone has created a web site, Measuring Worth, that tries to provide "price" data for very long periods of time.

    We can now compare the old reserve currency to the modern reserve currency and see what one should expect of the dollar exchange rate if in fact someone (like the IMF?) comes up with a replacement currency. We can see the dollar to pound exchange rate for more than 200 years was mostly stable in the low 20s during it's reserve period. Shortly after the first Bretton Woods agreement it started falling, and was again relatively stable for around 17 years (1950 - 1967). From that point on it enjoyed the roller-coaster thrill of the new world order of completely free exchange rates, apparently initiated by what Wikipedia called the "Floating" Bretton Woods. But in spite of that, the 2007 price was hardly different than 1967.

    In the end, after 200 years of currency history, the British pound lost it's reserve status and sits about about 1/2 it's value from the reserve days. The only clear currency-based investment choice we can see from the advantage of hindsight from 1949 to the present is converting pounds to gold rather than converting pounds into the new global currency reserve emerging in that day (the dollar). Our friends at Kitco have some nice gold charting tools where one can compare the performance of gold relative to the dollar, and with a little work, convert that price chart to gold in British pounds.

    We leave it as an exercise for the reader to analyze the choice between reserve currencies and stocks and bonds. But to argue that losing it's reserve status will ensure the "collapse" of the dollar is an exaggeration in light of reserve currency history. The real movers are more than just reserve status. When the data catches up with us, we'll look at foreign net purchase of U.S. debt in the early summer of 2009 and see how that theory is holding up.

    Wednesday, June 17, 2009

    The End of National Currency

    If the Council on Foreign Relations wasn't so full of influential powerful traditional men and women from around the world, I'd write this off as ranting from some deluded conspiracy theorist. But it's no joke -- these people really think like this and carry weight with people that matter.

    In "THE RISE OF MONETARY NATIONALISM", Benn Steil, Director of International Economics, argues that national currencies create nothing but trouble for the global economy. The premise is that the troubles we've seen are created by the inability to manage economic activity because of a lack of an organized over-arching system of "good" currencies so those dumb little "emerging" nations don't mess people up with their uninformed and inexperienced economic planning.

    I like the implications of the first part -- if we just had a lot fewer currencies, maybe one global one in fact, then we could regulate and manage a perfect economic world. Those darn national currency speculators are just nothing but trouble for everyone, wrecking all our lives. What we need are professionals to plan the global economy. He even goes so far as to say, "The economics profession has failed to offer anything resembling a coherent and compelling response to currency crises." Poor Benn, he appears to have been isolationg himself.

    George Reisman offers a much better answer to the many global crisis in his essay, "Our Financial House of Cards". Lo and behold, he's part of the economic profession, too! The reason you won't find this in prestigious [cough] institutions like the Council of Foreign Relations is it doesn't provide men and women with the power they want over other people's lives.

    It never ceases to amaze me how those who are afraid of the Moral Majority and "Right Wing Radical Religious Zealots" have no problem putting some other group in control over their private free-will behaviors. Oh no, we don't want religious slavery, but economic slavery, that's fine. How 'bout we just liberate ourselves from slavery, period?

    If you plan to be an investor for 30 years you might want to read these two points of view and consider how you'll protect yourselves when "they" sell the idea of one global currency. It shouldn't be too hard. Imagine how your little lone nation has messed up your finances, then imagine what it would be like if they do it on a global scale and remove your ability to allocate your assets in some safe harbor. I suspect it won't be a very obscure idea in the next 5 years when all the global money printing press operators have had their fill and we start reaping the consequences of our new love for Quantitative Easing.

    And all this time I thought it was the unregulated credit futures and derivative speculators that got us into trouble this time. Ha, so glad I now know better who the real villains are. Do you?